Sweden
March
5, 2007
As aging populations and shaky public
finances make overhauling pension systems a global priority, an initiative
implemented nearly a decade ago in Sweden
is looking like the pension world's next big thing.
By pegging public pensions to individual
earnings and overall life-expectancy rates, Sweden has given its citizens incentives to be more productive and retire later
-- and sidestepped the political paralysis that has stymied change
elsewhere.
Some Eastern European nations have already
ditched their struggling post-Communist systems and gone Swedish. Steps
taken in countries as diverse as Brazil
and
Russia
boast some Swedish elements. A World Bank book based on the Swedish model
has been translated into Chinese. And next month, Egypt's government will review plans to chuck the country's failing system for
a Swedish version.
"There's no magic solution to the
pension problem. But governments world-wide are looking at"
Sweden
, says Kent Weaver, political-science professor at
Georgetown
University
in Washington. "It's starting to be seen as the best among what are now seen to be
imperfect options."
Sweden
's plan -- designed in part by an American expatriate -- is conventional
in that current workers' contributions fund current retirees' benefits,
much as the Social Security system does in the
U.S.
But calculating payouts according to salaries and aging projections gives
it the flexibility to accommodate revenue and population shifts. If the
economy does poorly, the thinking goes, future pension payments will go
down. And the longer people in a particular age group are projected to
live, the smaller their pension payouts will be.
Or at least that is the theory. The
changeover was made in 1999, so not enough time has elapsed to thoroughly
test it. In fact,
Sweden's economy has done so well since 2003 -- when benefits started being
calculated in part under the new rules -- that pensioners have received
more than they would have under the old structure. The downside is that if
and when growth falters, retirees will get less. "It hasn't happened
yet, but it will," says Ole Settergren, director of the pensions
department at Sweden's Social Insurance Agency.
That approach is a break from the typical
pay-as-you-go system, which defines a guaranteed benefit in advance but
often saddles the state with underfunded obligations -- particularly when
times are bad.
Sweden's system "is not a good system
if you want to subsidize leisure," says Edward Palmer, a professor of
social-insurance economics at Stockholm's Uppsala University and a
Colorado native who helped design the plan.
It can be a good system, however, for
politicians wary of revamping pensions, because it allows them to defer to
a formula rather than promoting the unpopular options of later retirement
and smaller benefits. "The political discussions behind [things like]
increasing the retirement age are much more cumbersome than if it just
happens mathematically," says Robert Holzmann, senior director of the
World Bank's Social Protection unit in Washington.
Skeptics point out, however, that
politicians still could eventually be pressured to change the system if
benefits get too skimpy.
Sweden's plan has other critics. It is a tough sell elsewhere in
Western Europe
, where many see generous pensions as a right. Other critics include the
International Labor Organization, which holds that earnings-related
pensions should guarantee 40% of a person's prior average earnings.
Swedes, unlike the majority of Western Europeans, get no such assurance.
The system also preserves existing income inequality: Workers who earn
more get more when they retire.
In the U.S., Social Security tracks what people pay through the bulk of their
careers, but it reroutes contributions from wealthier citizens to prop up
poorer workers' pensions.
The bottom line of the Swedish model: Most
people will have to work harder to reap the kinds of pensions their
grandparents could take for granted. "It puts the cost of aging onto
the individual, rather than onto society," says Sarah Brooks, an Ohio
State
University
political-science professor who has studied the plan.
Last February, the World Bank endorsed the
Swedish plan as a possible antidote to pension woes world-wide. Economists
at the European Central Bank followed up last fall, highlighting Sweden's
approach for the 13-nation euro zone, where one-third of the population
will be older than 64 by 2050.
In countries with strapped budgets, the
Swedish plan's attraction is its premise that something is better than
nothing -- in other words, stingier payouts help ensure the system doesn't
collapse. That was crucial to persuading unions in
Egypt
to endorse that country's new Swedish-inspired pension plan. "They
know [the old plan] is generous, but they also know it will not be
there," says David Robalino, a World Bank economist who has been
working in Egypt.
In Poland, where a public-relations campaign helped ensure an enthusiastic
transition to a Swedish-style system in 1999, the fiscal benefits are
already clear. A recent European Union report said that, despite having
some of the worst demographics on the Continent, "the long-term
budgetary impact of aging in Poland
is the lowest in the EU."
Like Sweden, Poland
mandated that a slice of pension contributions go into private accounts
similar to a 401(k), where the money is invested in mutual funds. Swedes
contribute 18.5% of their salaries to the pension system; only a small
portion of that -- 2.5 percentage points -- is held in individual
accounts. Poles contribute a total of 19.52% of their gross salaries to
the system, with 7.3 percentage points going into private accounts.
The concept of individual accounts has been
key to selling the plan to Swedes.
Sweden
sends its workers statements -- mailed annually in bright orange envelopes
-- showing what they have put into their pension and what they would get
at retirement. The money isn't really there for them (it is being paid to
current retirees). But advocates say seeing it expressed as an individual
account should have the psychological effect of encouraging people to work
longer to win bigger benefits.
It may be working. Sweden's official retirement age is 61 years old. Since the change took effect,
the average age at which Swedes retire has risen to 63.
Even partially adopting the Swedish plan can
have benefits.
Brazil
doesn't send its citizens annual statements, and there is no
private-account component. But individual-contribution and life-expectancy
rates have been used to calculate private-sector pension payouts since
1999. Brazilian officials made the change after studying the Swedish
model, and they have seen costs fall since.
Perhaps the Swedish plan's biggest drawback
is that it remains relatively untested. The first wave of retirees who get
all their benefits based on the new model won't hit for another few years,
and the country hasn't suffered a major economic slowdown since adopting
the plan.
"It certainly has the virtue of
spelling out, in anticipation, what people have agreed should
happen," says Olivia Mitchell, director of the Pension Research
Council at the
University
of
Pennsylvania's Wharton
School. "But that doesn't necessarily mean that it will."
(image and article courtesy of wsj.com)
Copyright © Global Action on Aging
Terms of Use |
Privacy Policy | Contact
Us